The Bretton
Woods System is an interesting creature. It is often stressed that the system
looked very different than the way its founders originally intended in 1944. It
ushered in a period of rapid economic growth on a scale never seen before or
even after. While the system itself should be credited for some portion of the
success, the larger context of a post-war boom must be kept in mind too.
The
international monetary order as it existed prior to Bretton Woods, from 1914 to
1945, was such a disturbed period in human history that Winston Churchill
referred to it as the “Next 30 Years War.” Calling it a kind of monetary
“order” is probably an exaggeration. Prior to WWI, the monetary order referred
to as the Classical Gold Standard was literally destroyed. Countries not only
destroyed each other, but also their own economies and currencies in patriotic
fervor.
The Bretton
Woods System was a platform on which the unprecedented rise in the standard of
living prior to WWI might resume. Who would have guessed that a system of fixed
exchange rates and a world of immobile capital might yield such favorable
results? (Since the late nineteenth-century, no period was characterized by
such high degrees of capital immobility as that of Bretton Woods) Nonetheless,
even this system was wrecked by political considerations. This time it was American
fiscal exigencies.
The monetary
order was, nominally, underpinned by gold. After a round of devaluations of
around 30% in the late 1940s, the fixed exchange rate system was born. The
Sterling was revalued in terms of the Dollar, from $4 to $2.80 to the pound.
This was the opposite of what happened in 1925, when the British refused to
devalue the Sterling. One of the effects was that an overvalued Pound reinforced
existing structural unemployment by making exports less competitive.
However, the
problem lay with the new hegemonic status commanded by the dollar. In the
system, the dollar was pegged to gold at $35 an ounce. Every other currency was
pegged to the dollar. By anchoring the dollar to gold and the Rest of the
World’s currencies to the dollar, it was hoped that the new monetary order
would bring international monetary stability. And for a time, it did.
The dollar
became the world’s new international medium of exchange, not gold. It was
simply assumed that dollar denominated liabilities, bonds issued by the federal
government, were all backed by the
gold amassed at Fort Knox. While cashing in American paper for gold was allowed
(imagine the consequences if it was not!), American debt largely served as
collateral, an asset base, on the balance sheets of foreign central banks.
What if
everybody might want to cash in on these dollar denominated securities? Would
Fort Knox be able to accommodate everybody? Hypothetically, Robert Triffin
postulated, no. Hence, this particular issue was eventually termed the “Triffin
Problem.”
In hindsight, it
is easy to see that a little “benign neglect” by the American government might have
produced some unintended inflation, while the spillover effects extended into
other countries. Professor Nick Crafts calls these countries “inflation takers.”
At first, the expansion of the dollar served as a source of liquidity for
Europe – the point Professor Crafts makes in reference to the Marshall Plan.
However, the inflationary pressure originating from the dollar eventually came
to be known as “malign neglect,” because it was no longer in the new monetary
order’s interests that justified dollar expansion, but in the American
government’s interest.
The evidence
speaks for itself. The amount of monetary gold held as reserves in 1950 stood
at $35.3 billion. By 1973, it rose to only 43.1 billion. (At $35 an ounce, this
is not really a surprise. Then again, it did still provide the anchor for the
whole system) Another potential source of liquidity, the IMF’s Special Drawing
Rights, also saw a comparatively small expansion over the same period, from
$1.7 billion to $7.4 billion. A clue is in the figures representing foreign
exchange reserves, which were held in dollars (of course). Between only 1969
and 1973 this figure nearly quadrupled – standing at $32.4 billion in 1969 and
exploding to $123.1 billion in 1973.
While general
external dollar liabilities increased substantially as early as 1967, external
dollar liabilities held by monetary authorities (foreign central banks) skyrocketed
in 1970. So why did the United States break the post-war monetary order? The
War in Vietnam is the most obvious candidate, with the bombing of the North
Vietnam beginning in 1965. Additionally, I hypothesize that funding NASA during
this time period wasn’t cheap either. After all, the first moon landing was in
1969.
Isn't the answer simple mercantilism? The US' long-run balance of trade was changing for the worse, and they wanted to devalue.
ReplyDeleteOrder of Impact on the net international investment position of the US during Bretton Woods:
ReplyDeleteHeavy US foreign private investment> social security> Vietnam> French liquidation> and then maybe NASA.
Also Bretton Woods is either 1946-1971/73 in its broadest definition, or 1959-1968 in its narrowest. 1951 is a questionable start.